So, we have seen that bifurcations diagrams are a useful geometric device, a type of graph that lets us see, all at once, the different behaviors a dynamical system might have as a parameter is changed. In this lecture, I will focus on the phenomenon of bifurcations themselves. I think this is an important topic from dynamical systems, particularly for the study of complex systems. Bifurcations aren't as well-known, or flashy, or perhaps as exciting as the butterfly effect or strange attractors. But, I think they're important and definitely good to know about. So, I'll begin making this argument by return to the the logistic equation with harvest. So, here's the logistic equation with a harvest term. rP times 1 minus P over K. K is the carrying capacity and then h is the harvest, the number of fish, or whatever, that are caught every year. And, before we talk about the bifurcation diagram, just a reminder that the right-hand side of this equation is quite well-behaved. This is just an upside-down parabola, this term here, and the h just shifts the whole graph down. So, here is what that looks like for, say, for h equals 40, and as h gets larger this graph just slides down like this. But, this is a smooth function of P, a smooth function of h; it's differentiable, very nice and well-behaved. Ok, so as we've seen, the bifurcation diagram looks like this. And, here, I've just drawn in different colors the two different types of equilibria, or fixed points. So, red, this is the stable attractor and blue is the unstable attractor. So, let's think about this in terms of fishing in this model population, and h is the fishing rate, the number of fish that we allow to be caught or the pounds of fish or whatever, every year or every generation. So, when we are down here, we are doing no harvest at all; and, this red value up here, this is actually the carrying capacity, the equilibrium value in the absence of this harvesting. And, so then we begin, imagine we discover a lake or some people arrive there, and time to start fishing and we allow a certain amount of fishing. And, a little bit of fishing leads to a small decrease in the steady-state population, the equilibrium population of the lake. And, that makes sense, it would be surprising if anything else happened. When you start fishing, there will be less fish. But, maybe not such a big deal, there is a growth rate. You kill some fish; the fish grow back towards their carrying capacity. They don't actually hit the carrying capacity, but they come pretty close. Down here, this unstable equilibrium has gotten a little bit larger and that's not surprising at all. If, say, we are catching 40 fish a year, but there are only 20 fish in the lake then we're not going to be able to recover because we will have killed all the fish, and so that population would move down. So, if you start harvesting. If you start this fishing, one can imagine that if you start off with very few fish you'll just kill them all. So, that seems reasonable. So, lets continue thinking about what's going on up here, on this curve. So, maybe we've allowed fishing up to this rate and things are going pretty well. And, so a bunch of people ask to fish more because fishing is fun, or it's lucrative, or people are hungry and they want to eat fish. And, so we allow a bunch more fishing and then the population, the steady-state population, decreases a little bit more, but, not that much. And, all along this curve, a small increase in the fishing rate gives rise to a small decrease in the equilibrium population, seems to make really good sense. And, then we keep going, maybe we are out here and we decide, ok, let's do a little bit more fishing. Things have been going well. And, we allow a bit more fishing, and all of a sudden we end up over here. So, if h, the fishing rate is this high, then there is no steady-state population and the fish population would just crash. It would go right down to zero. But, the thing to note is, well, a couple of things, the steady-state, this red value, you might think that the equilibrium value would approach h smoothly. But, instead, it just sort of falls off a cliff. You can have a stable equilibrium here, but you can't have any stable equilibria for a population less than this. So we might think that this red curve should kinda go down and touch this, but the red curve just blinks out of existence right here. It's important to know that in this fishing scenario, we have control over h. That's something that could be set by policy and could be measured. We just count how many fish people catch. But, what this equillibrium population is wouldn't be observable, typically. There might be some clues that the fish suddenly get hard to catch. But, maybe, right, the population is still pretty large. You can imagine being out here, close to the point where you fall off this cliff and the fish suddenly die, with a small in increase in h. Still a lot of fish and so they can still be pretty easy to catch, it might not be really, it might not be immediately noticeable. So, the lesson here, the thing that I think is important, is that we can have a very sudden transition, a mathematically an instantaneous transition, and it's in a sense a discontinuous one where the population would go from an equilibrium here all the way down to zero. There is no equilibrium value in between these two points. So, we have this discontinuous behavior, even though this function is continuous and smooth can be. So, even a continuous and differentiable function that varies as function of h can have this sort of potentially disastrous and discontinuous behavior. One more possible scenario to note. So, imagine we're moving along this curve or somewhere along here, and we don't really, but we don't realize it because we can't really see this curve, so we just increase the fishing rate a little bit more and we start to plummet down here. Right, so the population is here. We allow allow too much fishing. The population starts to die off, maybe suddenly people aren't catching fish. We notice the fish stock is decreasing, and so the logical thing to do then might be to cut back on fishing. And, maybe we cut back on fishing a lot. So, that would move us back here. But, even doing that, once you are down here and population starts to crash, if you cut back on fishing even by a factor of 50%, you still might be in this region where the fish are still going to die. So, once you sort of move over this edge, you might need to reduce fishing entirely, or almost entirely in order to get back here and creep back up to this equilibrium value. So, again, I don't think these people actually use these models to, in a numerical way, to understand how fish rates behave. But, this does suggest that you can have a sudden collapse, that a stable point can disappear suddenly and without warning. And, it turns out that that's a fairly generic feature of differential equations, even ones that are smooth and continuous like this one.